66 research outputs found

    The Persistence of "Bad" Precedents and the Need for Communication: A Coordination Experiment

    Get PDF
    Precedents can facilitate successful coordination within groups by reducing strategic uncertainty, but they may lead to coordination failure when two groups with diverging precedents have to interact. This paper describes an experiment to explore how such coordination failure can be mitigated and whether subjects are aware of it. In an initial phase, groups were able to establish a precedent in a repeated weakest-link game, and in a second phase two groups with dierent precedents are merged into a larger group. As expected, this leads to coordination failures. Unlike most of the previous literature, subjects could endogenously choose to communicate in the merged group for a small fee. The results suggest that communication can mitigate the coordination failure in the merged group and, in most cases, leads to efficient coordination. However, subjects in particular from groups with an efficient precedent in the initial phase are inattentive to the potential coordination failure and choose not to communicate. This can have profound consequences since groups who fail to implement communication are unable to achieve efficient coordination in the second phase. The results may be useful for the understanding of how groups learn to solve coordination problems from past coordination success or failure.coordination, precedent, costly communication, cheap talk

    Social Relationships and Trust

    Get PDF
    While social relationships play an important role for individuals to cope with missing market institutions, they also limit individuals' range of trading partners. This paper aims at understanding the determinants of trust at various social distances when information asymmetries are present. Among participants from an informal housing area in Cairo we find that the increase in trust following a reduction in social distance comes from the fact that trustors are much more inclined to follow their beliefs when interacting with their friend. When interacting with an ex-ante unknown agent instead, the decision to trust is mainly driven by social preferences. Nevertheless, trustors underestimate their friend's intrinsic motivation to cooperate, leading to a loss in social welfare. We relate this to the agents' inability to signal their trustworthiness in an environment characterized by strong social norms.Trust, hidden action, social distance, solidarity, reciprocity, economic development

    Exclusion in the All-Pay Auction: An Experimental Investigation

    Get PDF
    Contest or auction designers who want to maximize the overall revenue are frequently con- cerned with a trade-off between contest homogeneity and inclusion of contestants with high valuations. In our experimental study, we find that it is not profitable to exclude the most able contestant in favor of greater homogeneity among the remaining contestants, even if the theoretical exclusion principle predicts otherwise. This is because the strongest contestants con- siderably overexert. A possible explanation is that these contestants are afraid they will regret a low but risky bid if they lose and thus prefer a strategy which gives them a low but secure pay-off.experiments, contests, all-pay auction, heterogeneity, regret aversion

    Exclusion in the all-pay auction: An experimental investigation

    Get PDF
    Contest or auction designers who want to maximize the overall revenue are frequently concerned with a trade-off between contest homogeneity and inclusion of contestants with high valuations. In our experimental study, we find that it is not profitable to exclude the most able contestant in favor of greater homogeneity among the remaining contestants, even if the theoretical exclusion principle predicts otherwise. This is because the strongest contestants considerably overexert. A possible explanation is that these contestants are afraid they will regret a low but risky bid if they lose and thus prefer a strategy which gives them a low but secure pay-off. -- Steht bei einer Auktion oder einem Turnier die Maximierung der Gesamtanstrengung aller Teilnehmer im Vordergrund, besteht ein Zielkonflikt zwischen der HomogenitĂ€t der Teilnehmer und der Teilnahme ausgesprochen starker Wettbewerber. Aus der theoretischen Literatur ist das sogenannte Ausschlussprinzip bekannt, das besagt, dass der leistungsstĂ€rkste Agent aus einer Gruppe von Teilnehmern ausgeschlossen werden sollte, wenn das LeistungsgefĂ€lle zu groß ist. Dieses Prinzip wird einem experimentellen Test unterzogen. Es zeigt sich, dass sich der Ausschluss des stĂ€rksten Teilnehmers nie lohnt, da sich dieser weit ĂŒber die Maßen anstrengt, sofern er an der Auktion teilnimmt. Die ĂŒbermĂ€ĂŸige Anstrengung ist umso prominenter, je ĂŒberlegener der stĂ€rkste Teilnehmer gegenĂŒber dem zweitstĂ€rksten ist. Dieses Verhalten kann mit einer Aversion gegenĂŒber dem GefĂŒhl des Bedauerns erklĂ€rt werden, das die stĂ€rksten Teilnehmer spĂŒren, wenn sie sich weniger anstrengen und in Folge den Wettbewerb verlieren.experiments,contests,all-pay auction,heterogeneity,regret aversion

    Social Relationships and Trust

    Get PDF
    While social relationships play an important role for individuals to cope with missing market institutions, they also limit individuals' range of trading partners. This paper aims at understanding the determinants of trust at various social distances when information asymmetries are present. Among participants from an informal housing area in Cairo we find that the increase in trust following a reduction in social distance comes from the fact that trustors are much more inclined to follow their beliefs when interacting with their friend. When interacting with an ex-ante unknown agent instead, the decision to trust is mainly driven by social preferences. Nevertheless, trustors underestimate their friend's intrinsic motivation to cooperate, leading to a loss in social welfare. We relate this to the agents' inability to signal their trustworthiness in an environment characterized by strong social norms.trust, hidden action, social distance, solidarity, reciprocity, economic development

    The Persistence of "Bad" Precedents and the Need forCommunication

    Get PDF
    Precedents can facilitate successful coordination within groups by reducing strategic uncertainty, but they may lead to coordination failure when two groups with diverging precedents have to interact. This paper describes an experiment to explore how such coordination failure can be mitigated and whether subjects are aware of it. In an initial phase, groups were able to establish a precedent in a repeated weakest-link game, and in a second phase two groups with di erent precedents are merged into a larger group. As expected, this leads to coordination failures. Unlike most of the previous literature, subjects could endogenously choose to communicate in the merged group for a small fee. The results suggest that communication can mitigate the coordination failure in the merged group and, in most cases, leads to efficient coordination. However, subjects in particular from groups with an efficient precedent in the initial phase are inattentive to the potential coordination failure and choose not to communicate. This can have profound consequences since groups who fail to implement communication are unable to achieve efficient coordination in the second phase. The results may be useful for the understanding of how groups learn to solve coordination problems from past coordination success or failure

    Information and Beliefs in a Repeated Normal-form Game

    Get PDF
    We study beliefs and choices in a repeated normal-form game. In addition to a baseline treatment with common knowledge of the game structure, feedback about choices in the previous period and random matching, we run treatments (i) with fixed matching, (ii) without information about the opponent’s payoffs, and (iii) without feedback about previous play. Using Stahl and Wilson’s (1995) model of limited strategic reasoning, we classify behavior with regard to its strategic sophistication and consider its development over time. In the treatments with feedback and full information about the game, we observe more strategic play, more best-responses to beliefs and more accurate beliefs over time. While feedback is the main driving force of learning to play strategically and for forming beliefs that accurately predict the behavior of the opponent, both incomplete information about the opponent’s payoffs or lack of feedback lead to a stagnation of best-response rates over time. ZUSAMMENFASSUNG - (Information und Erwartungen in einem wiederholten Normalformspiel) Wir untersuchen die Entwicklung von den Erwartungen ĂŒber das Verhalten des anderen Spielers und den Entscheidungen in einem wiederholten Normalformspiel. ZusĂ€tzlich zum Haupttreatment mit common knowledge ĂŒber das Spiel, Feedback ĂŒber das Ergebnis in der vorigen Runde und zufĂ€lliger Zuordnung der Spieler, gibt es Kontrolltreatments mit (i) festen paarweisen Zuordnungen der Spieler, (ii) ohne Information ĂŒber die Auszahlungen des anderen Spielers und (iii) ohne Feedback ĂŒber das Ergebnis der vorigen Runde. Mit Hilfe von Stahl und Wilsons (1995) Modell begrenzten strategischen Verhaltens klassifizieren wir das Verhalten der Teilnehmer im Hinblick auf die strategische Sophistikation. In den Treatments mit Feedback und vollstĂ€ndiger Information ĂŒber das Spiel nehmen strategisches Verhalten, beste Antworten auf die eigenen Erwartungen und die Akkuratheit der Erwartungen ĂŒber die Zeit zu. WĂ€hrend Feedback der Hauptgrund dafĂŒr ist, dass die Teilnehmer lernen, sich strategisch zu verhalten und korrekte Erwartungen ĂŒber das Verhalten des anderen Spielers zu bilden, fĂŒhren sowohl unvollstĂ€ndige Information ĂŒber die Auszahlungen des Gegenspielers als auch fehlendes Feedback zu einer Stagnation der Rate der besten Antworten ĂŒber die Zeit.

    Partner Selection in Public Goods Experiments

    Get PDF
    This paper studies the effect of introducing costly partner selection for the voluntary contribution to a public good. Subjects participate in six sequences of five rounds of a two-person public good game in partner design. At the end of each sequence, subjects can select a new partner out of six group members. Unidirectional and bidirectional partner selection mechanisms are introduced and compared to controls with random partner rematching. Results demonstrate significantly higher cooperation in correspondence to unidirectional partner selection than to bidirectional selection and random rematching. Average monetary effort for being able to choose a partner is substantially high and remains stable.Public goods, Partner selection, Experimental economics

    The Power of Sunspots: An Experimental Analysis

    Get PDF
    We present an experiment in which extrinsic information (signals) may generate sunspot equilibria. The underlying coordination game has a unique symmetric non-sunspot equilibrium, which is also risk-dominant. Other equilibria can be ordered according to risk dominance. We compare treatments with different salient, but extrinsic signals. By increasing the precision of private signals, we manipulate the available public information, which allows us to measure the force of extrinsic signals. We also vary the number of signals and combine public and private signals, allowing us to see how subjects aggregate available (and possibly irrelevant) information. Results indicate that sunspot equilibria emerge naturally if there are salient (but extrinsic) public signals. However, salient private signals of high precision may also cause sunspot-driven behavior, even though this is no equilibrium. The higher the precision of signals and the easier they can be aggregated, the more powerful they are in dragging behavior away from the risk-dominant to risk-dominated strategies. Sunspot-driven behavior may lead to welfare losses and exert negative externalities on agents, who do not receive extrinsic signals.coordination games, strategic uncertainty, sunspot equilibria, irrelevant information

    Information and Beliefs in a Repeated Normal-Form Game

    Get PDF
    We study beliefs and choices in a repeated normal-form game. In addition to a baseline treatment with common knowledge of the game structure and feedback about choices in the previous period, we run treatments (i) without feedback about previous play, (ii) with no information about the opponent’s payoffs and (iii) with random matching. Using Stahl and Wilson’s (1995) model of limited strategic reasoning, we classify behavior with regard to its strategic sophistication and consider its development over time. We use belief statements to check for the consistency of subjects’ actions with the stated beliefs as well as for the accuracy of their beliefs (relative to the opponent’s true choice). In the baseline treatment we observe more sophisticated play as well as more accurate beliefs and more best responses to beliefs over time. We isolate feedback as the main driving force of learning to play strategically and to form beliefs that accurately predict the behavior of the opponent.beliefs, experiments, strategic uncertainty, learning
    • 

    corecore